The first time I visited Kharkhiv, an industrial city in north-eastern
Sunday 28 March 2010
Rocket Science in Kharkhiv
Friday 19 March 2010
George Papandreou’s Third Act of Political Theatre
Prime Minister George Papandreou, emboldened by the success of his campaign to portray
Thinking about Government II – The Role of OSE
To illustrate my earlier post on government, I have a few examples of government operations from
OSE is a state-owned organisation which includes three major holdings:
a. EDISE – management of rail infrastructure
b. Erga OSE – project development
c. Gaia OSE – buildings and commercial centres
A fourth subsidiary, TrainOSE, was transferred out of the OSE holding structure and spun-off as a 100% government-owned, independent entity, for provision of transport services (drivers, conductors, scheduling, etc.)
The company employs 1,800 full-time staff (including TrainOSE employees, who have since been transferred), and is responsible for running both suburban and inter-city rail services. OSE does not include the Attika or
Some basic financial dimensions:
· In its 2008 Annual Report, OSE claims total debts of EUR 8.04 bln. Of this debt, EUR 964 mln was borrowed in 2008.
· Total turnover in 2008 was EUR 195.6 mln, as opposed to EUR 116.2 mln in 2007.
· Annual losses in 2008 were EUR 794,6 mln, compared to EUR 950.3 mln in 2007. This reduction in losses is not a result of better operating results, but due to the “sale” (or transfer) of TrainOSE to the government.
· Total payroll costs were EUR 274.2 mln in 2008, nearly EUR 90 mln higher than sales.
· The company estimates its fixed asset value at EUR 12.6 bln. Of this asset value, however, the majority concerns rail lines, equipment and technical infrastructure.
· OSE is owed over EUR 500 mln in VAT returns from the government.
· The company is committed to investing a further EUR 9.3 bln in the period 2008-2017, for track upgrades and expansion.
In 2008, the company changed its Board of Directors and President four times.
According to its 2008 Annual Report, OSE objective is to have satistfied citizens, either as passengers or as commercial clients; to achieve a better image in international markets, and to contribute as a productive factor to the commercial, industrial, processing, and tourist development of
OSE’s further objectives are:
· The direct and indirect creation of new jobs
· The attraction of new investors in the fields of logistics, transport, port expansion, movement of goods, etc.
· The freeing up of transport capacity on the national road network through the reduction of trucks on the road
· To contribute to the environment, given that rail transport comprises the most economic and the most ecological form of transport for passengers and goods.
In reading the Annual Report, I can’t help but be struck by a powerful sense of unreality. OSE has over EUR 8 bln in debt, which grows by about EUR 400-900 mln per year in new borrowing. In 2008, its sales accounted for EUR 195 mln; its losses were EUR 795 mln. Financial expenses alone (debt service) amounted to EUR 428 mln). Payroll costs are far higher than annual sales. The company is bleeding money: no amount of restructuring is going to be sufficient to change the situation.
Not a single objective mentioned in the OSE report has to do with reaching economic self-sufficiency. Perhaps the Board and President of OSE have already determined that this is impossible, in which case the only option left is to decide some nebulous goals which have little bearing on reality.
A further danger is the fact that, according to the findings reporting by a Commission set up by the Ministry of Finance, although OSE’s EUR 8 bln debt is guaranteed by the government, it has not been added to the government balance sheet.
Asset sales and/or privatisation will probably not be enough to recoup the EUR 8 bln loss. Although there is a high asset value, little can be sold off separate from the technical assets and rail lines.
My questions for the Greek government are the following:
1. Do we need a national railways organisation?
In the 19th and early 20th centuries, the expansion of the rail network was considered to be a strategic asset for economic and military purposes. However, this experience accrued mainly from countries such as
2. The privatisation option
Privatisation in the rail industry has been catastrophic, as the examples of the
3. Throwing good money after bad
How can the government justify, on economic terms, investing a further EUR 9 bln in OSE, when OSE already owes EUR 8 bln+? What will the financial impact of this investment be on OSE’s accounts? Why is it not mentioned in the 2008 Annual Report? Does the government still have the money, given its enormous debt, to make this investment?
4. The better transport argument
If a strategic argument for keeping OSE alive is to have more environmentally-friendly transport, or less-congested roads, what are the economic costs of the alternatives? How many trucks and passengers does OSE transport per year, and what is the net environmental benefit of transporting this number by rail as opposed by private or public transport? How many pubic busses could we buy for EUR 964 mln per year? How many trees could we plant? How many solar power installations or wind farms could we build?
5. The places of employment argument
If OSE has 1,800 employees, then one measure of the total cost of their employment in capital terms is EUR 535,556 per year. (Debt issued in 2008 / # employees). This is, by any objective measure, far too high, and given OSE’s debt needs, will rise every year. It would be much cheaper to pay them to stay home.
a.
b. Successive administrations have packed the organisation with political appointees, and launched grand investment programmes, for political and personal benefit in the form of bribes, kickbacks or other benefits.
c. The “strategic” value of OSE is not even zero: it is a huge liability in public finance, which will have to be paid by the Greek taxpayer, who has had absolutely no part in the decision-making concerning this “organisation”.
d. There are similarly no alternative sources of value given the costs involved: not in terms of environment, nor of employment, nor of transport.
e. The fact that the government has not declared the liabilities of OSE on its total debt is yet another example of financial manipulation.
f. Even assuming that a privatisation results in EUR 1 bln of income (which it won’t with the financial indicators already seen), at least EUR 7 bln in debt will have to be transferred to the government.
Wednesday 17 March 2010
Thinking about Government
A recent Facebook post on Cypriot agricultural subsidies prompted an interesting exchange of views between various friends on the role of government. I was impressed to receive responses which did not respond to the specific example given, but to the theoretical virtues of government. Since this issue set off so much debate, I’d like to add a first stab at a more coherent personal view of how I feel about the role of government, in theory and in practice.
Strengths / Necessities
The role of government should be to provide an objective service, usually of last resort, that is fair and which cannot be fulfilled with the same conditions by a private sector or NGO provider. Some domains, such as defence, law enforcement, the law itself, regulation of business sectors, protection of the environment and natural heritage, and international relations at the national and super-national level are clearly those of government.
These roles are also justifiable on the basis of efficiency and effectiveness. It is often better, for instance, to have a national police force, given the common nature of the law (and of human nature), rather than a series of regional or private police forces, providing of course this national force is honest, flexible and adaptable.
Risks / Weaknesses
The main risk is that governments are neither intelligent, nor responsive or flexible, and do not adapt quickly to changing conditions. One a precedent is set (e.g. a subsidy granted), it become very difficult to unwind that precedent due to changing business conditions. The European Union’s Common Agricultural Policy (CAP) or the subsidies offered to various businesses, are cases in points, especially when these create a dependency culture.
The second major risk is that government over-extends its role. Fortunately or unfortunately, the government cannot do everything, yet the standard impetus of internal decision-making (which our ministers often call “policy-making”) is precisely for government to do too much, particularly since this reflects on the personal prestige of political leaders and parties. The result is “mission creep”: situation where government organizations miraculously find more and more things to do, dominate a given sector, and strangle or suffocate all other alternatives.
Government and Political Parties
One of the main points of the recent discussion was the theoretical role of governments. In general, it’s easier to agree on the theory, than on the practice. Yet we live in a real world, where countless millions of consumers, business managers, government employees and others make millions of decisions. We also live in a world where, for Europeans at least, we claim to be a democracy, but the structure both of political decision-making, and political parties themselves, is fundamentally undemocratic and rigid. Political parties are characterized by a strange permanence of “elected” leaders, while democracies are characterized by a strange inability of their citizens to influence important political decisions, after an election has taken place.
The Athenian ideal of democracy (which was hardly a broad or stable democratic franchise) was quite different from the current national interpretation. Today in
Look at any European political party, and what will you see? Long-serving, career politicians who rarely face any personal responsibility for decisions made in office. This is arguably one of the major shortcomings of our current political system, since it creates a culture of impunity in which there are few real consequences for the political elite.
Government and Individual Politicians
Which leads us to another dilemma: are we sure that individual politicians are governing in the interest of the law, and of the country, or for their own narrower benefit? In the case of the
When speaking of the role of government, we should differentiate between theory and practice, where the practice is rarely as immaculate as the theory.
Government and Moral Hazard
If we are really in favour of equal opportunities and social equity, then we must answer the fundamental question on whether public money is really well spent. It’s far too easy to justify public spending as a benefit for “the poor” or “the disadvantaged”, particularly if this spending is the result of a government monopoly which restricts or removes any alternatives.
Given that the financial resources for government activities are ultimately derived largely from tax contributions of corporate and individual taxpayer citizens, it is not a moral imperative that services of the public good should be delivered solely by the public sector.
There are many sectors in
A Generalisation of Opposing Viewpoints
I like to think as government as the plumbing. Plumbing silently and humbly serves the vital functions of a house and the family that lives in it. When the plumbing breaks, it’s a crisis, and I can in a plumber to repair it, usually at low cost.
Our politicians, unfortunately, have a very different view of themselves. They tend to see themselves as protean heroes in the struggle of good versus evil. (Read any election campaign speech, and you will see what I mean) They rarely question the limits of their remit: once elected, they are free to roam at will, becoming increasingly arrogant and ubiquitous in the media. To justify their existence, it often seems that they must create a role for themselves, even if no role is really needed.
Obviously, I exaggerate: the functions of government are far more complex than that of a plumbing system. How can we connect the two viewpoints: those of the individual taxpayer, who wants a decent service at a fair tax and no poncing about, with the elected decision-makers who actually run government to further their political and individual careers?
Judging the Cost of Government
How can we tell government has over-extended itself? Usually when it has surpassed the financial limits in a political struggle to deliver higher public services or benefits. And this is what we see today. We have a society in which we, the taxpayers/citizens, have grown to expect the theory of public goods in healthcare, education, etc. but appear less willing to pay the price for them. Certainly, judging in terms of quality delivered, it would also appear that even now, we are paying too much for what is offered (at least from our viewpoint of public services in Greece and Cyprus).
The solution, from my viewpoint, is not to mindlessly extend the role of government as it is currently practiced, but to restrict and/or replace it, or at least the administrative elements of it. There is no reason, for instance, why more administrative functions interacting with citizens could not be placed online. There is no reason why at a certain point, a government should quite simply say “no” in terms of deciding a public investment.
We cannot continue the public spending track most countries are on. It will be necessary to adapt cuts in public spending, which have to be undertaken on a far better, economically rational basis than is currently the case. Implicit in this reduction of government expenditure is a restructuring of the public sector workforce and fixed positions. Do we really need, for instance, a Commissioner for Fisheries? Do we really need a Minister for Culture?
No Taxation without Representation
If we are going to view companies as legal organisms which will be taxed and regulated, then I suggest it is only fair that these entities are also given a voice in political decision-making. I do not recommend giving companies a vote, although this might make for an interesting simulation on a political theory class. But clearly, the role and energy of the corporate sector remains largely unused as a means of delivering a public good, since most companies are seen as passive respondents to the law, or to public policy. Yet the move towards “Corporate Social Responsibility” indicates that among many companies, there is a genuine interest in supporting key areas of public good: environment, charity work, education.
At the same time, other key issues have to be resolved:
· Why do most governments derive fewer taxes from companies than from individuals?
· Why do companies use lobbyists and “public affairs” consultants to pass favourable legislation?
· How can the system of “social partnership” work in practice?
The same principle applies to individuals: If we expect individual compliance with the law, or with a policy, it is only fair to allow individuals to influence the decision. Until now, such consultations are usually toothless exercises: in the future, a visionary democracy may separate, or re-define, the role of (a) elected politicians, (b) the permanent civil service, and (c) active citizens in decision-making and policy.
Certainly, my perception is coloured by my experience in
In fact, I believe the opposite is happening. We have constructed an elaborate experiment in social democracy in
As a result, we are being led into a situation where we will be forced to make changes, responding to symptoms rather than root causes of problems. And as such, we are making, and will continue to make, the wrong decisions.
Sunday 14 March 2010
A Consultant’s Guide to Tax Auditing. Part 1: How to Identify under-reported Income
We all know that in
Greek Debt Forecast March 2010
- Higher interest rates for sovereign debt;
- The EUR 7 bln debt of the Hellenic Railways Organisation (OSE);
- The state aid repayment and other debt provisions from Olympic Airways and its former employees;
- The continuing high and essentially unknown liabilities originating from state social security funds and hospitals;
- The opaque state of actual liabilities stemming from public-private partnership deals as well as interest rate swaps.
Saturday 6 March 2010
ND votes against the Greek austerity plan
Prime Minister George Papandreou has finally realised the gravity of